Another 'new kid on the block' for IB Economics students (new syllabus)
What is the national (public) debt?
It refers to what a government owes to all of its lenders: ‘Public debt
is created through government borrowing from individuals, corporations, institutions,
and other governments’ [from the New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics]
è
Debt is created when a government records a
‘budget deficit’: when G > T (when government expenditures exceed government
income which is mostly tax revenues (T) but may also be any one-off proceeds from
privatizations (the transfer [=sale] of state-owned assets to the private
sector) and any profits from state-owned enterprises)
è
It follows that the public debt is the sum of
all past budget deficits minus any budget surpluses [‘the public debt a
stock at any given point in time and represents the net accumulation of
the associated deficits over all previous time periods’; from the New Palgrave]
è
Given that a government borrows by issuing
bonds (=selling to whoever is willing to
buy these i.e. to lenders) it follows also that the debt is equal to the value
of all outstanding bonds (i.e. bonds that are held by its creditors and thus have
not yet ‘matured’ and been paid off)
è
Government bonds may be held by domestic
creditors (=lenders) or by foreigners (= external debt; denominated typically but
not necessarily in USD); bonds are held by individuals, firms, banks,
universities, pension funds, money managers etc. etc.
To compare the size of the debt of a country with other
countries or to determine the extent to which it is ‘sustainable’ , the
absolute ‘dollar’ size of the debt is expressed as a proportion of GDP (scaling
for the size of the economy). We thus focus
on the debt to GDP ratio.
(perhaps subscribe for free to Finance & Development, an IMF publication; the IMF will send you at your address every quarter the newest issue: https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/fandd
Perhaps read read: (a) https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/fandd/issues/2022/03/Balancing-act-Gaspar
(b) https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/fandd/issues/2022/03/Deciding-when-debt-becomes-unsafe-Blanchard
Perhaps also check out the post on Jason Furman here: http://www.ibeconomics.org/2021/09/the-national-debt-expressed-as.html
Note:
A more appropriate metric of debt is the ‘debt
service over GDP’. The reason is
that debt is a ‘stock’ variable (measured at a point in time, (say, December 31st
of the year) whereas GDP is a ‘flow variable’ (measured over a time period,
typically over a year). If Janice earns income
of $100000 per year and has borrowed to buy a house $300000 dollars (so owes banks
$300000 (her debt)), then her debt to her income ratio is 300000/100000 or 300% of her
income - but if she needs $10 000 per year to service her debt then the debt
service to her income ratio is 20% and what matters to Janice is what she pays
off annually to her creditor (the bank). That is why the debt service to GDP ratio is more informative than the simple debt to GDP ratio.
Cost of high debt
Cost of debt servicing:
-
a. Opportunity cost of the funds sacrificed as
these funds could have been invested by the government in pro-growth and
pro-development goals i.e. on infrastructure investments, on education and on
health care services; debt servicing thus restricts the ‘discretionary
spending’ ability of the government
-
b. Policymakers cannot as easily adopt expansionary
fiscal policy (G up; and/or T down) since It would lead to more debt accumulating
-
c. If debt is mostly domestically held (as it is in
Japan) and if the country (unlike Greece- a member of the Eurozone) can issue its own currency, then, if
debt is getting dangerously high, the government may be tempted to ‘monetize’
its debt i.e. to print more money to pay off its creditor; but then there is
higher risk of inflation (remember Friedman’s helicopter money drop: ‘too much
money chasing after too few goods’); on the other hand, if an attempt is made to pay off foreign
lenders (in USD) by printing more domestic currency then the currency will massively depreciate also creating higher inflation
as prices of imported goods will rise.
·
Impact on credit rating:
Credit rating agencies (CRAs) measure the credit
risk of debt for all types of investors. 'Their measurement of credit risk
includes default probabilities…and serve an economic purpose as they reduce asymmetric
information about issuers that investors face when making investments’(from
the New Palgrave). Three agencies (Moody’s, Finch, Standard & Poor’s: the ‘big
three’) rate the debt of countries and assign a ‘grade’. Top rated debt (bonds) is AAA which means
ultra-safe: creditors will definitely get their money back. But if these
agencies come to a realization that a country’s debt is becoming riskier then
it will downgrade it. But then lenders will demand a ‘risk premium’ i.e. to
earn higher interest rates. This automatically makes the debt burden heavier so
a ‘feedback loop’ may be initiated that may lead to default [and here comes the IMF with its rescue
packages (conditional lending at preferential interest rates) that (once 'agreed' upon) hopefully signal to private investors that the country is back on track
to become creditworthy].
·
Impact on future taxation and government
spending:
This is where ‘austerity policies’ come into play: the debtor country is forced (‘agrees’= more like some ‘arm twisting’) to slash G and to raise T in order to achieve ‘primary budget surpluses’ (a primary budget surplus is recorded when government spending excluding debt servicing is less than government income (T) so that the government can start lowering its debt; Greece was required for a number of years to achieve primary budget surpluses equal to 3% of its GDP which were huge and inflicted significant pain on mostly low income Greek households
-
Note an influential paper by Alberto Alesina and
Silvia Ardagna that tried to show that fiscal contraction will not have the
expected Keynesian result (to lead to recession) but will lead to expansion
(referred to as ‘expansionary fiscal contraction’); Why? Because according to A&A the private sector would see
that the government is rationalizing (cutting) its spending that would result in greater
confidence levels and thus more investment and consumption from the private sector. Proved to not really be the
case. Krugman called this the ‘confidence fairy’)(see https://www.bruegel.org/blog-post/expansionary-fiscal-contractions-and-uk-experiment)
-
Also note paper by Kenneth Rogoff and Carmen Reihhart of Harvard that showed that when the debt to GDP level exceeds 90% then an economy will
fall into recession. A graduate student at UMass @Amherst trying as an exercise
in econometrics to duplicate their results couldn’t. He and his advisor found
that R&R had (a) excluded from their sample countries which if they were
included would NOT have led to recession but to continued growth and (b) that
there were coding ‘errors’ in their excel files. Paper was largely discredited
but it had already damaged many in debt-ridden economies.
-
The ‘mea culpa’ of the IMF: The IMF had underestimated the Greek
multiplier so that the agreed upon cut in Government expenditures by the Greek government led to a
much bigger than projected decrease in national income (which meant that many
more than expected suffered a loss in jobs/ income). Olivier Blanchard, then Chief
Economist at the Fund (now at PIIE), was forced to issue a correction of the multiplier which
was referred to as Blanchard’s ‘mea culpa’.
No comments:
Post a Comment